By Bruno Baránek, who holds a PhD in Economics from Princeton University, and Vitezslav Titl, an Assistant Professor of Law & Economics at Utrecht University School of Economics. Originally published at VoxEU.

No country is safe from the risks posed by connections between politicians and private companies; scandals involving conflicts of interest plague governments around the world. Using a detailed dataset from the Czech Republic, this column demonstrates that ties between political parties and boards of government contractors lead to overpriced contracts without any corresponding gains in quality for citizens and consumers. The authors also explore how and when increased oversight can mitigate the adverse effects of such connections, informing policy on conflicts of interest in public procurement.

Scandals involving conflicts of interest are prevalent in politics across all countries. For example, during the early stages of the COVID-19 pandemic, nearly a third of the suppliers awarded contracts for personal protective equipment (PPE), such as masks and gloves for healthcare workers, had connections to politicians or senior officials in the UK (Conn and Evans 2020). Similar scandals have occurred in many other countries (for additional examples, see Baranek and Titl 2021). These conflicts of interest raise legitimate concerns about inefficiencies and corrupt practices, leading to reduced competition and innovation, with negative effects on economic growth (Baslandze et al. 2018) and welfare (Varghese et al. 2020). To address these issues, most countries have implemented rules to manage conflicts of interest. The EU, for instance, introduced rules in its 2018 Financial Regulation aimed at preventing the adverse effects of conflicts of interest. Similarly, US law – specifically, 18 US Code § 208 and the Code of Federal Regulations – prohibits officials from taking actions involving entities in which they, their spouses, children, or partners have a financial interest.

The public procurement market is a major channel through which political connections can be exploited. The scale of public resources allocated through these markets is enormous, with public institutions globally awarding contracts worth approximately 12% of GDP annually (Bosio et al. 2022), or about one-third of all government expenditures (OECD 2013). In Baránek and Titl 2024, we examine the additional costs incurred in public procurement due to connections between politicians and companies. Specifically, we trace these links through politicians’ memberships on company boards or direct ownership of companies. When government bodies and companies share ties to the same political party, we observe contract overpricing of approximately 6%. We also explore how and when increased oversight can mitigate the adverse effects of such political connections. By doing so, we aim to inform policymakers how to design rules regarding conflicts of interest in public procurement.

To address these questions, we draw on recent research using a detailed dataset from the Czech Republic that tracks firms’ personal connections to political parties through (supervisory) board memberships and ownership by political candidates. In the Czech Republic, a relatively small proportion of public tender suppliers have personal links to political entities, representing approximately 1% of all suppliers. However, these connected suppliers account for 7% of the total value of public tenders, indicating that they win a disproportionately large share of public procurement contracts. While this disparity is not necessarily problematic, it does raise important concerns. On the one hand, personal connections could facilitate cooperation between firms and government agencies, potentially improving efficiency. On the other hand, and this is a common concern, preferential treatment of connected firms may lead to contracts being awarded to less competitive entities, resulting in inefficiencies. It could also foster increased corruption and create additional bureaucratic hurdles for non-connected firms (Shleifer and Vishny 1993).

Analysing public procurement data from 2006 to 2018, we find that contracts awarded to politically connected firms lead to adverse contract-level outcomes. These contracts are overpriced by approximately 6%, with no corresponding improvement in quality. The dataset encompasses public bodies across all levels of governance, including municipalities, regions, central government, and other government-controlled entities such as state-owned companies. To measure the effect of political connections, we compare contract prices when a firm has an active connection to the party controlling the government entity (i.e. the buyer) with the prices of contracts awarded by the same buyer when the firm had no active connection to the party in power. A firm’s connection changes when politicians to whom the company is linked are either voted out of or elected into office. Over the period studied, 11 elections resulted in approximately 370 changes in supplier connection status, providing a rich dataset for causal analysis. The main findings hold even when the analysis is restricted to close elections, making it difficult to predict in advance which political parties will control the relevant public body. In such cases, the allocation of contracts is effectively random, allowing for a cleaner causal interpretation.

However, even if a contract awarded to a politically connected firm is overpriced, the overall effect on the public sector and general welfare could be positive if the quality of the delivered service is significantly higher. To assess this possibility, we examine whether politically connected firms deliver higher-quality services. Measuring quality is challenging due to the general lack of available data, so we apply a text-analysis-based method proposed by Baránek (2020), which uses contracts’ short descriptions, award dates, and other details to estimate the total lifetime cost of a construction project. This approach allows us to track the number and cost of repairs for the studied construction projects. The findings reveal a small and statistically insignificant negative effect on the quality of projects delivered by connected companies. In the figure below, we illustrate the effects on prices and quality, highlighting the stark contrast between significant price increases and the absence of quality improvements. Note that the quality measure is based on inverse quality, meaning it reflects insignificantly higher lifetime costs.

Figure 1 Impact of a political connection on contract-level price and quality

Note: Price effect measured in relative percentage terms with respect to the baseline engineering estimates; i.e. the figure shows a 6% overpricing above engineering costs. Inverse quality is measured using overall lifetime costs of projects consisting of follow-up repairs of construction projects.

From a policy perspective, it is important to understand how favouritism in public procurement operates. While some procurers may restrict competition or use discretion to favour specific firms (Orlando et al. 2018), the primary channel seems to be the tailoring of project specifications to benefit connected companies. This involves customising technical requirements to make the favoured bidder more competitive. While the misuse of discretion or limiting competition can often be addressed with straightforward policy solutions, the challenge is more complex when favouritism arises from contract tampering. Existing policies target the most obvious issues associated with political ties, such as conflicts of interest, but these regulations only apply when a politician holds a concurrent position in a private firm. They do not cover more subtle connections between political parties and companies. Our research suggests that enhanced monitoring of contract delivery can mitigate the negative impacts of political affiliations, particularly when oversight is conducted by a higher governmental authority over a subordinate one. Given the significance of this finding for policy, and the fact that we cannot definitively establish causality, we recommend that this topic be explored further in future studies.

References available at the original

Print Friendly, PDF & Email
This entry was posted in Politics, The dismal science on by Lambert Strether.

About Lambert Strether

Readers, I have had a correspondent characterize my views as realistic cynical. Let me briefly explain them. I believe in universal programs that provide concrete material benefits, especially to the working class. Medicare for All is the prime example, but tuition-free college and a Post Office Bank also fall under this heading. So do a Jobs Guarantee and a Debt Jubilee. Clearly, neither liberal Democrats nor conservative Republicans can deliver on such programs, because the two are different flavors of neoliberalism (“Because markets”). I don’t much care about the “ism” that delivers the benefits, although whichever one does have to put common humanity first, as opposed to markets. Could be a second FDR saving capitalism, democratic socialism leashing and collaring it, or communism razing it. I don’t much care, as long as the benefits are delivered. To me, the key issue — and this is why Medicare for All is always first with me — is the tens of thousands of excess “deaths from despair,” as described by the Case-Deaton study, and other recent studies. That enormous body count makes Medicare for All, at the very least, a moral and strategic imperative. And that level of suffering and organic damage makes the concerns of identity politics — even the worthy fight to help the refugees Bush, Obama, and Clinton’s wars created — bright shiny objects by comparison. Hence my frustration with the news flow — currently in my view the swirling intersection of two, separate Shock Doctrine campaigns, one by the Administration, and the other by out-of-power liberals and their allies in the State and in the press — a news flow that constantly forces me to focus on matters that I regard as of secondary importance to the excess deaths. What kind of political economy is it that halts or even reverses the increases in life expectancy that civilized societies have achieved? I am also very hopeful that the continuing destruction of both party establishments will open the space for voices supporting programs similar to those I have listed; let’s call such voices “the left.” Volatility creates opportunity, especially if the Democrat establishment, which puts markets first and opposes all such programs, isn’t allowed to get back into the saddle. Eyes on the prize! I love the tactical level, and secretly love even the horse race, since I’ve been blogging about it daily for fourteen years, but everything I write has this perspective at the back of it.